My
local grocery store has an affiliated gas station that offers ten cents off per
gallon for every $100 spent on groceries. I provoked a discussion on Facebook
by asking whether I should use my accumulated points every time I fill up the
tank, or whether it makes more sense to only use the option periodically in
order to get a bigger discount.
We
quickly agreed that so long as I only fill up when my tank is nearly empty, I
should always use the points available. In other words, there is no advantage
in strategically holding on to my points.
This
was what I had been doing, and the exercise was mostly just a nod to the
serious economics geeks who have befriended me on the social network. What
concerned me, however, was that some people — presumably fans of Austrian
economics — thought there was something fishy in the whole concept of price
discounts.
In
the present article I want to explain the standard economic rationale for
coupons, senior-citizen discounts, and other forms of "price
discrimination."
Price Cuts: A Zero-Sum Game?
Some
of the participants in the Facebook discussion were wary of the store's
program. They argued that if my shopping at the grocery store allowed me to get
cheaper gas, then the store was either charging too much for groceries or was
charging everybody else too much for gas. In other words, the cynics thought
that clearly the store wasn't giving me the discount out of altruism, and so
somebody else (maybe me) must have been the one really "paying" for
my cheap gas.
Despite
the trivial example, the whole episode underscores two themes in free-market
economics that at first appear contradictory. On the one hand, economists often
cynically point out, "There ain't no such thing as a free lunch." Indeed,
some economists use this phrase so frequently that
they abbreviate it as "TANSTAAFL."
On the
other hand, free-market economists going back at least to the classicals have
stressed that social cooperation is a win-win scenario. The classical
economists demonstrated that the mercantilists were wrong when they
viewed their own nation's prosperity as a threat to all other nations, and vice
versa. The principle of comparative advantage (perhaps inaccurately attributed
to David Ricardo) and Bastiat's eloquent
description of Economic
Harmonies illustrate the theme that the presence of a
"winner" in an economic transaction does not imply that there
must be a corresponding "loser" out there.
How
then to classify my grocery store's practice of offering cheap gas, or more
generally the phenomenon of price discounts? On the one hand, we should indeed be cynical and realize that the businesses aren't
showering the community with "free" gifts; the businesses are
definitely getting something out of the practice. On the other hand, the
positive-sum outcomes ubiquitous in market transactions should remind us that
the businesses' gain needn't come at the expense of others in the community.
Coupons and Other Price Discounts: Examples of Price Discrimination
Many
of the apparent puzzles in business pricing behavior fall away once we take
into account two empirical facts: First, people are different when it comes to
their willingness to buy more or less of a good at various prices. (In jargon,
economists say that different consumers have different demand curves or schedules for various
products and services.) Second, business owners initially don't know this
information about the buying proclivities of their potential customers.
If a
business only charges a single price to all of its customers, then —
disregarding non-pecuniary motivations — the business tries to set the price in
order to maximize (monetary) profits. The problem is that this one-price-fits-all
policy will probably leave many potential win-win exchanges "on the table."
"The
positive-sum outcomes ubiquitous in market transactions should remind us that
the businesses' gain needn't come at the expense of others in the community."
For
example, suppose a bar owner decides that charging $5 for a beer will maximize
his profits. If he charged more than that, his sales would decline such that
his total profits would go down, even though he would make a higher profit per
beer. Going the other way, if he charged lower than $5 per beer, he would sell
more units, but not enough to compensate for the smaller margin per beer.
That's why (by stipulation) $5 is the profit-maximizing price if the owner has
to charge all customers the same amount.
But
what if the owner tries something creative, like letting women drink for free?
This is the popular practice known as "Ladies Night." If women end up
ordering 10 percent of the drinks on a particular Ladies Night, the cynic might
conclude that the bar owner has to raise the price of beer sold to the men
(perhaps to $5.50 or so in order to "pay for" the discount given to
women. This doesn't follow, however. Even at the same price of $5, the men
might now order more beers during
the night, because hanging out at the bar is more enjoyable when there are more
women (who have been enticed into coming by the free drinks).
More
generally, targeted price discounts allow businesses to engage in "price
discrimination," which is the practice of offering different prices to
different segments of the clientele. Movie theaters often offer cheaper prices
to students and senior citizens, not because
it's cheaper to have them sit in the theater, but because they are typically
more careful with their spending than middle-aged adults with jobs. The use of
coupons and rebates (which require the customer to mail in a form or go to a
website) also help a business segregate the "cheapskates" among their
customers from the people who are too busy to worry about saving a few dollars.
In
all of these cases, the granting of special pricing for certain groups
need not harm
the groups paying full freight.
For
example, if a movie theater in a small town were barred from giving child,
student, and senior discounts — and instead had to charge one ticket price for
all customers — it might not be able to stay in business. It would hardly help
the middle-aged adults to have a "fair" pricing policy with no
theater in town. This example shows the pitfalls in thinking about "the
cost" of providing a seat in a movie theater and deriving the
"fair" price that a theater ought to charge all customers.
Readers
need to recall the ever-present discipline of market competition. If the use of
coupons, rebates, and other strategies allows businesses to initially extract
higher profits from their customer base, then this success will attract more
firms into the industry. Prices will tend to be pushed down for all customers, even
those paying full freight.
Conclusion
Pricing
gimmicks such as student discounts, mail-in rebates, and "early-bird
specials" make perfect sense once we consider the actual situation a
business owner faces. Customers have different preferences and will not respond
in identical ways to various prices. The business owner initially doesn't know
which customers are sensitive to price and which are not. By taking advantage
of correlations with other observable traits (such as a customer's age or
willingness to clip coupons), the business owner can tailor his pricing and
seize more win-win exchanges.
By Robert P. Murphy
5 comments:
Hello sir,
I understand the gimmicks of the retailers behind their giving heavy discounts.Apart from the points mentioned in the article,sometimes their prior motive is the clearing of old stock,and sometimes they want to improve sales(viz,it is better to sell an expensively manufactured product at a lower price at loss than not selling it at all,thereby incurring more loss).
What I don't understand here sir,is that,how do you explain the behaviour of the e-retailers who offer discounts all the time,both off seasons and on ?Is it a win-win for both,the seller and the buyer ?
Dear Shrishti,
Happy to learn your economic and commercial understanding of things..
Its a complex question. The argument is, since the online stores are always offering a 'Never Before Price', will it create a win win for the buyer and seller? The issue is, we are not aware of the 'mark up price'. As we discussed in class today, the moment the mark up price is made public, all of us will be shocked ! In case a buyer is able to offer Discounts 24x7, it needs investigation rather than praise.
In fact, I am worried about the hidden charges which are camouflaged within the price. How can a seller offer free transport / home delivery when we know that there good amount of transport costs... How is it that they are able to still exist in market by giving 50% to 60% Discounts? The real issue here is what is unknown rather than the known 'Discounts'..
I like the curiosity in the whole debate. In today's information age, the more you know, the less you know..
Hope I have been able to answer through more questions :)
Warm Regards,
Arun
sir on the point where you told about free home-delivery and shipping for the online market. there is one more point that i would like to point out and that is how on purchase from some bank debit cards they provide you with an extra discount and how in many products they are able to sell by giving additional discounts if we buy till some extent(like 10% discount after purchase of 2000)
In my view this is one of the intelligent selling techniques of the buyers to maximize the producer surplus which is necessary in one way to maximize profits also to increase the welfare of the producer market as a whole. But when we look at the other side of the coin i.e. the buyers side we come to know the fact that consumers are being exploited by the gimmicks of these producers which creates pressure on only one group of consumers thus creating the problem of dissatisfaction among only one group of the buyer community. Moreover the sellers know the nature of the buyers i.e. these buyers long for getting something more in return when they spend their money on something that is a buyer is always a rational buyer and always would want to maximize his utility. They follow this pattern by gimmicky in the sense that they either give discounts to one section of the buyer community as pointed out in the article like only to the students or only the aged citizens which in turn exerts pressure on the youth of the community. Other ways could be to alter the quality of the product because in no way, we know that ,the producer want to decrease the profit so either they play with the quality of the product or they play with the quantity of the product because every seller would want to at least cover the cost of production in addition with a margin of profit which some or the other way they manage to cover through the price that they set.Besides discount other sale promotion techniques are refunds,quantity deals,product combination,instant draws and assigned gifts ,samples, lucky draw and so on. But the producer market sometimes fail to understand the demerits. These techniques may instill the feeling in the consumer that there is no demand for the product in the market and hence would reflect crisis also spoils the image of the product in the market.
Dear Sonakshi,
Impressive analysis and application of what we have learnt in class. What you have written is as good as a published article. The observation about youth behavior and promotion technique is pretty true.
The comment by Toshit takes us to the world of financial economics where every intermediary silently enters our markets and keeps on making money without our knowledge. The Debit card and Credit card companies do this all the time. They charge the people who are receiving money and in some cases even the buyer is charged.
Overall it is right to say that markets have many hidden actors. More we understand them,more we realize about the functioning of markets clearly.
Good job both of you for sharing this interesting and eye opening information.
Warm Regards,
Arun
Post a Comment